The Benefit of Acting Now to Reform Social Security

The three most important numbers in the Social Security reform debate are as follows: 218, 60 and 1. That is the number of votes any reform plan must receive in the House, the Senate and the White House to become law. One barrier to doing the politically hard work of agreeing to a Social Security reform is the fact that we can continue paying scheduled benefits for another quarter of a century even with no reform.  A year ago, this plus the fact that health care costs are a bigger source of the long term deficit would have led me to say that we should deal with health care costs first and that we have time to address the real shortfalls of Social Security later. I have changed my mind, and think that addressing Social Security sooner rather than later should be a top priority.  In part, I changed my mind because of the current impasse over health care reform, and the likelihood that it will be very difficult (impossible) to get any further movement ahead on addressing health care costs until after the legal challenges to the individual mandate are completed.  In addition, studying some basic charts from the Congressional Budget Office (CBO) helped to convince me that we need to act sooner, rather than later on Social Security in order to avoid the drastic nature of the fixes that will be required the longer we wait to act.  Three basic charts from the CBO’s July 2010 document on policy options for Social Security will help me to illustrate.


Figure 3 shows the projected revenues (dashed blue line) and scheduled Social Security benefits (dark blue line) from 2009 until 2080.  This figure shows the default Social Security fix, which is a large across the board benefit cut somewhere around 2037. This will be triggered under current law when the revenues flowing into the program are less than the benefits flowing out, and there are no longer any governmental securities that were bought over the past 25 years when revenues were greater than benefits, to make up the difference.  When this takes place, current law says that benefits will have to be cut to make the taxes flowing in match the benefits flowing out each year.  Several things about this graph.  First, with no change to benefits or taxes, the benefit cut required in 2037 or so would be very large (the near vertical line dropping by about 1% of GDP in 2037). This would be a tremendous benefit cut for beneficiaries, many of whom are dependent upon Social Security for a large portion of their income. Second, 2037 is 26 years away, which is not right around the corner.  It is true we could do nothing this year, and it wouldn’t make that much difference.  However, if you delay in this manner (wait until next year!) for another decade or so, then you are halfway to the very large drops with less time to implement an alternate change.

The next figure (Figure 4 from the CBO report) demonstrates what taking some immediate action (in this case reducing scheduled benefits starting in 2012) does to the problem–it both pushes further into the future the point at which a large benefit drop will occur, and it also makes the size of the necessary drop smaller.  It is true that Figure 4 demonstrates a strategy of making smaller cuts now to avoid bigger ones in the future.  However, something must be done, and beginning to act sooner would smooth out the changes which, in turn, will give people more time to plan. This seems preferable to me.  My point here is not to argue for a particular Social Security reform option, just to demonstrate that beginning to act now is important to avoid the most jarring changes later.

The final figure (Figure 5) more clearly demonstrates the effect of starting a policy earlier, as opposed to later.  The reform option shown is a 2 percentage point increase in the Social Security payroll tax (phased in slowly), and the 3 lines show the long range impact on the ability of Social Security to pay benefits if the payroll tax increase begins in 2012, 2022 and then what happens if it is not increased.  Under current law and no change, the scheduled benefits are larger than payroll taxes and all trust fund securities will have been redeemed around 2037 (dark blue line) meaning that benefits will have to be cut sharply in order for revenues to match outlays.  This is the same story told on the other two graphs, just in a slightly different way.  However, if an eventual 2 percent increase in the payroll tax were started in 2012 (light blue solid line), then Social Security would be solvent until 2080, meaning it could pay the scheduled benefits for the next 69 years because of the imposition of this tax increase starting in 2012.  If the same size payroll tax increase were delayed a decade and begun in 2022, then Social Security would be solvent and able to pay scheduled benefits until around 2055, at which point a steep benefit cut would be necessary without further action. Thus, a delay of a decade in beginning a slow tax increase reduces the ability of Social Security to pay scheduled benefits by 25 years.

My primary point here is not to argue for a given Social Security fix, but to argue for one to be developed sooner, rather than later. By acting now with either benefit cuts, tax increases or most likely a mixture of the two, we will signal our seriousness on the deficit and can begin addressing the long range problems of Social Security. We will be able to ease into changes over longer periods of time, and not face the very large and sudden benefit cuts that would be required with no action. Action taken now will allow people to plan for the future.  The longer we wait, the fewer options we will have, and the more painful they will likely be for the most vulnerable and dependent upon Social Security.  Most people say there is no way we would allow the large benefit cuts in Social Security that will be required in 2037 if no action is taken, and I think I agree. However, at some point we will have to take action to turn this general sentiment into a reality. We should develop a compromise proposal and act now.

Update: I clarified that CBO scenario option 2 (Fig. 5) is a 2 percentage point increase in the payroll tax rate that would gradually begin in 2012, or 2022, and rise by 0.1% per year (0.05% employer/0.05% employee) per year until the full 1%employer/1% employee increase was realized.

 

 

 

 

About Don Taylor
Professor of Public Policy (with appointments in Business, Nursing, Community and Family Medicine, and the Duke Clinical Research Institute), and Chair of the Academic Council at Duke University https://academiccouncil.duke.edu/ . I am one of the founding faculty of the Margolis Center for Health Policy. My research focuses on improving care for persons who are dying, and I am co-PI of a CMMI award in Community Based Palliative Care. I teach both undergrads and grad students at Duke. On twitter @donaldhtaylorjr

9 Responses to The Benefit of Acting Now to Reform Social Security

  1. steve says:

    Is that a 2% increase for all or just the 2% on the currently exempted income that you mentioned before?

    Steve

  2. Don Taylor says:

    @Steve
    In the CBO options doc http://www.cbo.gov/ftpdocs/115xx/doc11580/07-01-SSOptions_forWeb.pdf it is option 2, which is a 2 percentage point increase in the payroll tax (shared employer/employee) with no change in the wage limit, starting in 2012. This changes the rate by increasing the tax by 0.1 percent per year through 2031 (it would go up 0.05 employer/0.05 employee in each year). In 2031 it would be 2 pct points higher, with wage limit indexed as it currently is done. There are 30 options they model in the document. Page XI in the summary has a long chart that gives a sense of the magnitude in the degree of ‘fix’ in terms of % GDP of the various options.
    Don

  3. Lynn says:

    Why is raising the wage limit not considered in these scenarios? 0.1% of $1 million brings in a whole lot more than 0.1% of $30,000. How long would social security be solvent if the wage limit was removed? For those on the upper end, the social security tax results in a lower loss of utility than for those on the lower end, yet they don’t have to pay the tax on their full incomes. I’m not for “gouging the rich”, but I believe that everyone should be required to pay the set percentage of income, regardless of level of income – whether rich or poor – since all will benefit from these contributions.

  4. Don Taylor says:

    @ Lynn
    I just picked two (of 30) scenarios that CBO modeled to demonstrate the impact of starting sooner, rather than later. Options 4-9 that CBO considered (in the linked report in the post and in the comment above yours) include increasing the amount of wages that are subjected to the Social Security payroll tax in some way or another. Option 4, I believe, makes the existing rate applicable to all wages, and would produce about the same amount of ‘fix’ as does the option 2 (starting to slowly raise the rate in 2012). You could obviously have several tweaks on both tax and benefit side.
    Don

    • Lynn says:

      Don,

      How do you see the impact of slowly increasing the tax percentage differing from raising the tax ceiling for social security? Are there economic advantages to one over the other? I would think raising the tax ceiling would be less harmful to business and lower-income employees than would be raising the tax ceiling. I’m not sure if 7.5% tax on income above the current ceiling would be seriously detrimental to those paying it. What is your perspective on this?

      Lynn

  5. Sebastian Lohrn says:

    I believe that the reform of social security must change. 2% Would be fair for all because of mejoraria thus the quality of health care.

    Sebastian Lohrn
    Findrxonline

  6. Don Taylor says:

    @richard
    I agree with you….if the take home of my post was there is no problem then I have failed….
    Don

  7. Don Levit says:

    Richard;
    Excellent point about the cost of redeeming the bonds. If this was a real insurance program, as Roosevelt envisioned, there would be no redemption of Treasury bonds through the use of general revenues.
    That was not what Roosevelt meant when he wanted the program to be self-sustaining.
    In addition, the redemption of those bonds is not only a current expense as you mentioned, but it also increases the deficits. When the so-called surplus was being tapped, it reduced the deficit.
    In addition, that portion that is redeemed “transforms” from intragovernmental debt to debt held by the public. That means the more “serious” debt is finally growing, while keeping the total debt the same. All those years of surpluses provided a skewed view of the actual deficits. In addition, while using the loans from the trust funds for current budgetary impact, using for current expenses and lowering the deficits, the other side – the liability to the Treasury was deferred many years, until the pay out fronmthe trust fund excceded the pay-ins (excluding interest).
    That’s enough “float” to rise all boats!
    Don Levit

  8. Mark Fishman says:

    Social Security funding and benefit payouts should be considered as part of a comprehensive overhaul of our tax system. Please read the press release below about the tax reform plan that accomplishes this goal.

    FOR IMMEDIATE RELEASE

    Los Angeles, CA – The publication of Fishman’s Framework for Tax Reform heralds the introduction of the tax reform plan that will save our middle class. It lowers taxes for individuals and corporations yet raises a $1 trillion dollars more revenue than our current tax system.

    The additional revenue solves Social Security’s long term funding problem, creates and fully funds National Health Care and expands public education to include college free of charge. It also solves each states fiscal crisis.

    Fishman’s Framework for Tax Reform is only 18 pages long and comes with commentary, tax revenue estimates and five year budget projections. Additionally, there are seven appendices that prove that this tax reform plan lowers taxes for everyone and funds all government programs while running a budget surplus.

    Fishman’s Framework for Tax Reform is available to read free of charge at: http://www.serioustaxreform.com

    contact: mark@serioustaxreform.com
    Fishman’s Framework for Tax Reform, Video Lectures

Leave a reply to Don Taylor Cancel reply